Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning.
All Rights Reserved. May not be
scanned, copied or duplicated, or
posted to a publicly accessible
website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
PowerPoint Slides
© Luke M. Froeb,
Vanderbilt 2014
Investment Decisions:
Look Ahead and Reason Back
5Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
In Our Previous Lecture…
● Opportunity Cost
● Fixed and variable Costs
● Marginal analysis
● How contracts can be made better
2Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
SUMMARY OF MAIN POINTS
● Investments imply willingness to trade dollars in the present for
dollars in the future. Wealth-creating transactions occur when
individuals with low discount rates (rate at which they value
future vs. current dollars) lend to those with high discount rates.
● Companies, like individuals, have different discount rates,
determined by their cost of capital.
● The NPV rule states that if the present value of the net cash flow
of a project is larger than zero, the project earns economic profit
• Although NPV is the correct way to analyze investments, not all
companies use it.
● Break-even quantity: equal to fixed cost divided by the
contribution margin. If you expect to sell more than the breakeven quantity, then your investment is profitable.
3Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
SUMMARY OF MAIN POINTS
● Some costs are avoidable costs and others are
unavoidable.
• Possible decision to shut down business. If the benefits of
shutting down (you recover your avoidable costs) are
larger than the costs (you forgo revenue), then shut
down.
● Sunk costs once incurred are irretrievable.
• Possible vulnerability to post-investment hold-up.
● Relationship-specific investments where parties are
locked into a trading relationship with each other.
• Anticipate hold-up.
4
continuedINTRODUCTOR
Y
ANECDOTE
Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
WACC and Future Cost
● In summer 2007, Bert Matthews was contemplating purchasing a 48-
unit apartment building.
• The building was 95% occupied and generated $550,000 in annual profit.
• Investors expected a 15% return on their capital
• The bank offered to loan Mr. Matthews 80% of the purchase price at a rate
of 5.5%
● Mr. Matthews computed the cost of capital as a weighted average
of equity and debt (WACC).
𝐵
𝐠+ 𝐵𝐠= 𝐵𝐵
.2*(15%) + .8*(5.5%) = 7.4%
• Mr. Matthews could pay no more than $550,000/7.4% = $7.4 million and still
break even.
● Mr Matthews decided not to buy the building. A good decision – one
year later, the cost of capital was 10.125%. Mr. Matthews could offer
only $5.4 million for the building.
5Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Background: Investment Profitability
● All investments represent a trade-off between
possible future gain and current sacrifice.
● Willingness to invest in projects with a low rate
of return, indicates a willingness to trade current
dollars for future dollars at a relatively low rate.
• This is also known as having a low discount rate (r).
• Individuals with low discount rates would willingly
lend to those with higher discount rates.
• Discounting helps you figure out if future gains are
larger than current sacrifice.
6Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Compounding
● To understand discounting, let’s first look at
compounding:
(future value, k periods in the future) = (present value) x (1 + r)K
● Example: If you invest $1 (present value) today at a
10% (r), then you would expect to have $1.10 in one
year.
• In two years, $1 becomes $1.21 = $1.10 x (1+0.1)
● A good compounding rule of thumb: “Rule of 72”:
If you invest at a rate of return r, divide 72 by r to get the
number of years it takes to double your money
7Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Discounting
● Discounting (the inverse of compounding):
Present value = (future value, k periods in the future)
(1 + r)k
● Example: At a 10% r, $1 is worth:
• Next year: ($1)/1.1 = $0.91
• Two years: ($0.91)/1.1 =$0.83
● Discussion: If my discount rate is 10%, would I
lend to or borrow from someone with a discount
rate of 15%?
• What does this say about behavior?
8Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Example: Nashville Pension Obligations
● The city of Nashville uses discounting to decide how
much to save for future pension obligations.
● For a pension that pays out $100,000 in 20 years,
with a discount rate of 8.25% Nashville must save:
• $100,000/(1.0825)20 =$20,485
• If the city invests the $20,485 and earns 8.25%, then the
savings will compound in 20 years – unrealistic!
• High savings rate that may not be returned. A more realistic
discount rate would be 6.5%, which would lead to saving
$28,380.
9Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Determining the Profitability of Investments
● Remember the simple rule: discount the future benefits of
an investment, and compare them to the current cost.
● Companies use discount rates, which are determined by
cost of capital.
• A company’s cost of capital is a blend of debt and equity, its
“weighted average cost of capital” or WACC
● Time is a critical element in investment decisions
• Cash flows to be received in the future need to be discounted to
present value using the cost of capital
● The NPV Rule: if the present value of the net cash flows
is larger than zero, then the project earns more than the
cost of capital.
10Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
The NPV Rule In Action
● Consider two projects that each require an initial
investment of $100
• Project 1 returns $115 at the end of the first year
• Project 2 returns $60 at the end of the first, and $60 at the
end of the second
• The company’s cost of capital is 14%
11
• Project 1 earns more than the cost of capital. Project 2 does not.Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
NPV and Economic Profit
● Projects with a positive NPV create economic
profit.
● Only positive NPV projects earn a return higher
than the company’s cost of capital.
● Projects with negative NPV may create
accounting profits, but not economic profit.
● In making investment decisions, choose only
projects with a positive NPV.
12Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Another Method: Break-Even Quantities
● The break-even quantity is the amount you need
to sell to just cover your costs
• At this sales level, profit is zero.
● The break-even quantity is:
Q=FC/(P-MC)
FC: fixed costs P: price MC:marginal cost
• (P-MC) is the “contribution margin” – what’s left
after marginal cost to “contribute” to covering fixed
costs
13Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Break-Even Example: Nissan Truck
● Nissan’s popular truck model, the Titan, had only two
years remaining on its production cycle. Redesigning
the “Titan” would cost $400M.
• Cost of capital was 12%, implying annual fixed cost of $48M
• Contribution margin on each truck is $1,500
• Break-even quantity is 32,000 trucks
• The decision to redesign or not came down to a break-even
analysis
● Nissan had a 3% share of the market, implying only
12,000 Titan sales per year – not enough to break even.
● Instead they decided to license the Dodge Ram Truck,
which reduced the fixed cost of redesign, and gave a
lower break-even point.
14Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Deciding Between Two Technologies
● In 1983, John Deere was in the midst of building a
Henry-Ford-style production line factory for tractors
• Unexpectedly, wheat prices fell dramatically reducing
demand for large tractors
● Deere decided to abandon the new factory and
instead purchased Versatile, a company that
assembled tractors in a garage using off-the-shelf
components
● Deere chose one manufacturing technology over
another
• A discrete investment decision – the factory had big FC and
small MC, Versatile had small FC but bigger MC
15Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
John Deere: Right Decision?
● Was purchasing Versatile the right choice?
● It depends… on how much John Deere expected to sell.
• Suppose the capital-intensive technology would
involve $100 FC and $10 MC
• Suppose Versatile’s technology had $50 FC and $20 MC
• To determine break-even quantity (point of indifference),
solve for the quantity that equates the costs: $150 for 5 units
• If you expect to sell less than 5 units, choose the
low-MC technology
• If you expect to sell more than 5 units, choose the
low-FC technology
16Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
John Deere Lesson
● John Deere made the right decision by acquiring
Versatile.
● Rule: Do not invoke break-even analysis to
justify higher prices or greater output.
● Managers sometimes believe they must raise
prices to cover fixed costs or they must sell as
much as possible to make average costs lower
● These are extent decisions though!
• They require marginal analysis, not break-even
17Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
The Decision to Shut-Down
● Shut-down decisions are made using break-even
prices rather than quantities.
• The break-even price is the average avoidable cost
per unit
• Profit = (Rev-Cost)= (P-AC)(Q)
● Shutting down is different to closing the business
● If you shut down, you lose your revenue, but you
get back your avoidable cost.
• If average avoidable cost is less than price, shut down.
18Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Cost Taxonomy
● Example: FC=$100, MC=$5, and you produce 100 units/year
● How low of a price before you shut down? IT DEPENDS
● It depends on which costs are avoidable
• Long-run: fixed costs become avoidable so they are included
in the shutdown price
• Short run: they are unavoidable and should not be included
in the shutdown price
19
Fixed Costs
(avoidable in long run)
Variable Costs
(avoidable in short run)
Avoidable
Costs
Unavoidable
or “Sunk” Costs
CostsCopyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Sunk Costs and Post-Investment Hold Up
● Sunk costs are costs that are unavoidable
● If sunk costs are present then the incentives may
change once the cost is incurred
• Possible ‘hold up’ problem
● Before making a sunk cost investment, ask what
you will do if you are held up.
● What would you do to address a hold up?
20Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Sunk Costs and Post-Investment Hold Up Example
● National Geographic can reduce shipping costs
by printing with regional printers.
• To print a high quality magazine, the printer must buy a
$12 million printing press.
• Each magazine has a MC of $1 and the printer would print
12 million copies over two years.
• The break-even cost/average cost is $7 = ($12M / 2M
copies) + $1/copy
• BUT once the press is purchased, the cost is sunk and the
break-even price changes.
• The magazine can hold up the printer by renegotiating the
terms of the deal – the break-even price falls to $1.
21Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Possible solutions
● The transaction options are:
• Spot-market transactions
• Long-term contracts
• Vertical integration
• Vertical integration refers to the common ownership of two
firms in separate stages of the vertical supply chain that
connects raw materials to finished goods
• Discussion: How is vertical integration a solution to hold up?
● Contractual view of marriage
• Long-term contracts induce higher levels of
relationship-specific investment
22Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Relationship-Specific Investments
● Investment is more valuable inside the
relationship
• Relationship-specific investments can act like sunkcosts
• Possible hold-up problem
• Value of investment changes between prior and post
decision-making
● Think about the opportunity cost of acting
outside the relationship
23Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
Relationship-Specific Investments
● Contractual view of marriage
• Long-term contracts induce higher levels of
relationship-specific investment
● Bi-lateral investment in the relationship
• The other partner’s position matters as well
● Reputation effects
• Cost of doing business with others may increase
depending on behaviour
24Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
In Conclusion…
● Discounting
• Net present value (NPV)
● Break-even analysis
● Sunk costs
• Hold-up problem
● Relationship-specific Investments
25Copyright ©2016 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly acce ssible website, in whole or in part.
©Manuel Gutjahr/Vetta/Getty Images
In Our Next Lecture…
● Simple pricing
● Elasticities
• Price
• Income
• Cross-Price
● Stay-even analysis
26